SwePub
Sök i SwePub databas

  Extended search

Träfflista för sökning "L773:0921 8009 "

Search: L773:0921 8009

  • Result 1-50 of 245
Sort/group result
   
EnumerationReferenceCoverFind
1.
  • Gössling, Stefan, et al. (author)
  • Ecological footprint analysis as a tool to assess tourism sustainability
  • 2002
  • In: Ecological Economics. - 0921-8009. ; 43:2-3, s. 199-211
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This article has the aim to provide a methodological framework for the calculation of ecological footprints related to leisure tourism. Based on the example of the Seychelles, it reveals the statistical obstacles that have to be overcome in the calculation process and discusses the strengths and weaknesses of such an approach. As many tropical island-states depend heavily on foreign exchange earnings derived from visitors arriving by air, special attention is paid to the use of energy associated with air travel. Furthermore, implications of the findings for national greenhouse inventories are discussed. Finally, as the Seychelles have safeguarded a wide range of ecosystems in protected areas, which are for their existence ultimately dependent on financial resources derived from tourism, the question is raised if long-distance travel can be a means to safeguard biodiversity. (C) 2002 Elsevier Science B.V. All rights reserved.
  •  
2.
  •  
3.
  •  
4.
  • Lewan, Lillemor, et al. (author)
  • Knowledge and recognition of ecosystem services among the general public in a drainage basin in Scania, Southern Sweden
  • 2002
  • In: Ecological Economics. - 0921-8009. ; 42:3, s. 459-467
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Human preferences are likely to depend on such things as knowledge and information, propaganda and advertising, and formal (laws) and informal (norms) institutions. We focus on knowledge about how nature works and how this may be manifested in recognition of ecosystem services among the general public. Participants and non-participants in a plant nutrient abatement programme with detention ponds in a river drainage area in Scania, Southern Sweden, were asked to rank some selected ecosystem services, classified as visible services, invisible services and services involving human activities in nature. Three studied groups of local actors were originally not familiar with the concept of ecosystem services, but the concept was easily grasped. The results of the study include the following findings: (1) The groups of local actors were consistent in ranking the groups of visible and invisible services higher than the group of services involving human activities, but there were considerable differences in their ranking of individual services. (2) The generally high priority given to invisible services can partly, but not fully, be explained by the existence of the abatement programme. (3) There was uncertainty regarding relationships among and the relative importance of different ecosystem services. (4) Some informants had multiple preferences. In fact the role people chose to play may have larger impact on preferences than the level of information. (5) Several interviewees objected to the idea of ranking services, and preferred to view nature as a whole. The results are discussed from a knowledge perspective, and we conclude that a widespread recognition of ecosystem services in policy and economics cannot be expected until the general public has gained some critical level of basic knowledge about functions in nature.
  •  
5.
  • Carlsson-Kanyama, Annika, et al. (author)
  • Food and life cycle energy inputs : consequences of diet and ways to increase efficiency
  • 2003
  • In: Ecological Economics. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 44:03-feb, s. 293-307
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Food consumption is one of the most polluting everyday activities when impacts during product life cycles are considered. Greenhouse gas emissions from the food sector are substantial and need to be lowered to stabilise climate change. Here, we present an inventory of life cycle energy inputs for 150 food items available in Sweden and discuss how energy efficient meals and diets can be composed. Energy inputs in food life cycles vary from 2 to 220 MJ per kg due to a multitude of factors related to animal or vegetable origin, degree of processing, choice of processing and preparation technology and transportation distance. Daily total life cycle energy inputs for diets with a similar dietary energy consumed by one person can vary by a factor of four, from 13 to 51 MJ. Current Swedish food consumption patterns result in life cycle energy inputs ranging from 6900 to 21,000 MJ per person and year. Choice of ingredients and gender differences in food consumption patterns explain the differences. Up to a third of the total energy inputs is related to snacks, sweets and drinks, items with little nutritional value. It is possible to compose a diet compatible with goals for energy efficiency and equal global partition of energy resources. However, such a diet is far from the Swedish average and not in line with current trends.
  •  
6.
  •  
7.
  •  
8.
  • Gudmundsson, Henrik, et al. (author)
  • Sustainable development principles and their implications for transport
  • 1996
  • In: Ecological Economics. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 19:3, s. 269-282
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • 'Sustainable mobility' has been adopted as an overall objective for European transport policy, and similar intentions are expressed in other parts of the world. However, little has been done to define what 'sustainable mobility' would actually imply for our understanding and assessment of transport. We suspect that this much used term could merely end up acting as a lubricant to the very development it was meant to challenge: The ever increasing movement of people and goods. In this article we attempt to place transport in the context of sustainable development principles. We emphasise the need to include principles of development (increasing well-being and equity) as well as sustainability (preserving natural and man-made capital). Four such principles are suggested, taking inspiration from Herman Daly and others. We then turn to explore the main features of transport, establishing a comprehensive transport concept. The concept combines a systems perspective with a service perspective. Omitting either one would disable a complete consideration of sustainable development. Our confrontation of the four principles with the reality of current transport trends gives rise to several critical implications. The most important of which relate to the contribution of transport to depleting natural capital and quality of life. Moreover, we are also forced to challenge the value of increasing mobility itself, if other forms of access may provide relevant substitutes. The article thereby outlines some conceptual foundations for a transport policy that could qualify as sustainable.
  •  
9.
  • Gustafsson, Bo (author)
  • Scope and limits of the market mechanism in environmental management
  • 1998
  • In: Ecological Economics. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 24:2, s. 259-274
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This paper tries to evaluate the role of the market mechanism in environmental management and warns against reductionist views on the causes and remedies of environmental damages. According to some of these views, proper pricing of the environment and extensive use of market mechanisms in environmental management would solve environmental problems. But various conditions tell against such simplifications, namely: the complex causality behind environmental damages; the complexity of the functions and values of nature; as well as limitations of the market mechanism in coping with the functions and services of nature. Several of those limitations—the difficulties of defining and enforcing property rights to nature's functions and services; the pervasiveness of externalities conditioned by the public goods characteristics of many environmental functions and values; the difficulties in enticing, processing and using information about environmental goods; and the high transaction costs caused by all these circumstances—often rule out contracts and trading of environmental services. It is less known that the basic cause of market existence and extension, namely specialization and division of labour, have negative environmental effects. With respect to environmental policy, conceptual problems are analyzed. While all kinds of environmental management mechanisms have a regulatory function, only quantity mechanisms, as a subset of incentive mechanisms, are market mechanisms. The choice of relevant environmental policy instrument is conditioned by many considerations. The issue of the superior efficiency properties of market mechanisms in environmental management is not yet settled satisfactorily; extensive empirical tests are still lacking.
  •  
10.
  • Hammer, Monica, et al. (author)
  • Enhancing transdisciplinary dialogue in curricula development
  • 2001
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 38, s. 1-5
  • Journal article (other academic/artistic)abstract
    • A crucial step towards realizing transdisciplinary understanding is to address transdisciplinary issues in university curricula, and to train students in critically analyzing and understanding disciplinary metaphors. We present an experimental exercise at Stockholm University with the aim of finding a constructive way to introduce transdisciplinary elements in disciplinary courses and thus increase student awareness of disciplinary metaphors. The exercise required a minimum of formal university decision procedures and thus circumvented the institutional barriers that tend to obstruct the establishment of full transdisciplinary programs.
  •  
11.
  • Huitric, Miriam, et al. (author)
  • Development and government policies of the shrimp farming industry in Thailand in relation to mangrove ecosystems
  • 2002
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009. ; 40:3, s. 441-455
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Intensive shrimp farming arrived in Thailand during the 1980s and developed virtually unregulated until 1987. Subsidised by the government, it quickly became an important export industry and Thailand has been the world's largest producer of tiger shrimp since 1991. However, the development of the shrimp farming industry in Thailand over the last 20 years in relation to its use of mangrove ecosystems is an example of sequential exploitation of natural resources witnessed through the shift in farm development from one region to another. This sequential exploitation has caused widespread degradation of mangrove ecosystems, and the benefits of the industry may be less than perceived as a result of subsidies and environmental and social impacts. This study follows the development of shrimp farming in Thailand from the 1940s to 1997 and studies national legislation and associated government policy as examples of driving forces behind this development. From our findings it appears that the development of legislation has not followed the same pace as the development of the industry, neither temporally, nor in content nor implementation, and contradictory policies have arisen.
  •  
12.
  • Rönnbäck, Patrik, et al. (author)
  • Illuminating the need for ecological knowledge in economic valuation of mangroves under different management regimes — a critique
  • 2000
  • In: Ecological Economics. - Amsterdam : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 35:2, s. 135-141
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This is a commentary on a paper by Gilbert and Janssen (Gilbert, A.J., Janssen, R., 1998. Ecol. Econ. 25, 323–346) that deals with valuation of management alternatives for the Pagbilao mangroves, Philippines. Our main critique focuses on the undervaluation of fisheries as well as the inability to quantify the value of ecological services and internalize aquaculture’s environmental costs. In addition, the sustainability criteria set up for the aquaculture management alternatives is open to debate. These weaknesses affect the result of Gilbert and Janssen’s analysis so that the value of the unexploited mangrove forest is underestimated, and the value and sustainability of converting the forest into aquaculture ponds are overestimated. If applied to decision-making, the erroneous results from this partial cost–benefit analysis may have dire consequences for the mangroves and coastal communities of Pagbilao.
  •  
13.
  • Rönnbäck, Patrik (author)
  • The ecological basis for economic value of seafood production supported by mangrove ecosystems
  • 1999
  • In: Ecological Economics. - Amsterdam : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 29:2, s. 235-252
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • The undervaluation of natural products and ecological services generated by mangrove ecosystems is a major driving force behind the conversion of this system into alternative uses. This trend of undervaluation is partly due to the difficulty involved in placing a monetary value on all relevant factors, but lack of ecological knowledge and a holistic approach among those performing the evaluation may be even more important determinants. This article identifies and synthesizes ecological and biophysical links of mangroves that sustain capture fisheries and aquaculture production. Fish, crustacean and mollusc species associated with mangroves are presented and the ecology of their direct use of this system is reviewed. Through a coastal seascape perspective, biophysical interactions among mangroves, seagrass beds and coral reefs are illustrated. The life-support functions of mangrove ecosystems also set the framework for sustainable aquaculture in these environments. Estimates of the annual market value of capture fisheries supported by mangroves ranges from US$ 750 to 16 750 per hectare, which illustrates the potential support value of mangroves. The value of mangroves in seafood production would further increase by additional research on subsistence fisheries, biophysical support to other ecosystems, and the mechanisms which sustain aquaculture production.
  •  
14.
  • Sundkvist, Åsa, et al. (author)
  • Strengths and limitations of localizing food production as a sustainability-building strategy : - an analysis of bread production on the island of Gotland, Sweden
  • 2001
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 37:2, s. 217-227
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • In this paper we analyze the environmental consequences of local small-scale versus centralized large-scale bread production and the potential for self-sufficiency in bread in a Swedish island community. Mills and bakeries located on the island of Gotland in the Baltic Sea were compared with large-scale production systems on the Swedish mainland. The results show that bread production in local bakeries requires more total energy input per kilogram of bread than the industrial bakery, mainly due to inefficient technology. On the other hand, the analysis shows that emissions of CO2, SO2 and NOx are smaller from bread produced in the small local bakeries than from big bakeries on the Swedish mainland. This is because the transportation routes are much shorter for bread from the small bakeries and because oil is more frequently used for heating the ovens in large and medium sized bakeries. The present local production of flour on Gotland does not satisfy the local demand, but there is a potential for increased self-sufficiency. Farms on the island produce large amounts of bread grain, but only a small fraction (2%) is used in local flour production, while the rest is exported or used as animal fodder. Thus the region has a large potential to produce enough flour for its local population and thus to become less dependent on imports. However, using more locally produced bread grain to produce flour in local mills, improving energy efficiency in small-scale mills and bakeries, changing consumer behavior and internalizing environmental costs of transportation are crucial measures in achieving this goal.
  •  
15.
  • Söderbaum, Peter, 1937- (author)
  • Actors, ideology, markets : Neoclassical and institutional perspectives on environmental policy
  • 1994
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 10:1, s. 47-60
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This essay is a critical examination of three well-known textbooks of neoclassical environmental economics  concerning their treatment of environmental policy. Dynamic efficiency in the sense of Cost-Benefit Analysis of a monetary kind is not the value-neutral instrument to project and policy evaluation it purports to be. Measuring willingness-to-pay and other market values does not solve many problems if the issue is one of world view, ideology and life-styles. As an alternative to conventional approaches. a more open attitude to various ideological standpoints in society is recommended.Neoclassical textbooks emphasize the government as the main agent in environmental policy and classify policy instruments as either belonging to the command-and-control or the economic incentives category. A broadening of perspective is here suggested in the sense ofincluding many more agents of environmental policy; for instance business companies and public interest groups. Environmental policy starts rather at the level of individuals than governments. A distinction is made between monetary and non-monetary incentives and disincentives as ways of influencing behavior, and alternatives to the neoclassical view of man, business, markets are suggested for purposes of understanding social change.
  •  
16.
  • Söderbaum, Peter, 1937- (author)
  • Neoclassical and institutional approaches to development and the environment
  • 1992
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 5:2, s. 127-144
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Institutional economics is suggested as a more fruitful approach to environmental problems than the now dominant neoclassical paradigm. The historical background of institutionalism in the United States and Europe is given as well as th main characteristics of this approach, i.e. holism, emphasis on institutional arrangements, pattern modelling and emphasis on the political element of economics. Differences between neoclassical and institutional economics are elaborated with respect to the concept of economics (reductionist versus holistic), the approach to decision-making (aggregated versus highly disaggregated), and the view of social and institutional change (public choice versus actor-network approach).
  •  
17.
  • Söderbaum, Peter, 1937- (author)
  • Values, ideology and politics in ecological economics
  • 1999
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 28:2, s. 161-170
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Ecological economics is built on a value-commitment to study environmental issues and to contribute constructively to a more sustainable development path. However, many ecological economists still hesitate, it appears, to depart too much from other scholars by openly addressing issues of value and ideology. In this essay, the role of the scholar's orientation with respect to values and ideology is addressed. It is observed that not only scholars but also actors in society are guided by their 'ideological orientation'. This leads to the idea that some of the weaknesses of Economic Man and 'profit maximizing firm' assumptions can be mitigated by introducing a Political Economic Person and a Political Economic Organization.
  •  
18.
  • Söderholm, Patrik, et al. (author)
  • Pricing environmental externalities in the power sector: ethical limits and implications for social choice
  • 2003
  • In: Ecological Economics. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 46:3, s. 333-350
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • During the last decade, a series of valuation studies have made attempts at estimating the external environmental costs of various power generation sources. The purposes of this paper are: (a) to explore some of the ethical limits of the economic valuation of environmental impacts; and (b) to analyze what the implications are of these limits for the social choice between different electric power sources. Environmental valuation based on welfare economic theory builds on restrictive behavioral foundations and can only partly model moral values, although such values are an essential part of people's preference towards the environment. In addition, public preferences are seldom exogenously given as is commonly assumed in economic theory, but are instead formed in public discourse. For this reason, the range of electricity externalities where economic valuation (and thus cost–benefit analysis) should be applied is likely to be narrower than often assumed. After analyzing the scope, methodology and the results of the so-called ExternE project, the paper concludes that many power generation externalities are either inherently ‘new’ or inherently ‘complex’. In these cases, the initial challenge lies not in ‘discovering’ private preferences, but in specifying the conditions for public discourse over common ways of understanding what the pertinent issues are about. This implies that research on the environmental externalities of power generation must, in addition to refining the theory and the applications of existing non-market valuation techniques, also address the instruments and content of political and moral debate.
  •  
19.
  • Hornborg, Alf (author)
  • Unpacking the black box of 'energy technology' : How abstraction and resource fungibility obscure ecologically unequal exchange
  • 2023
  • In: Ecological Economics. - 0921-8009. ; 214
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Transitions to low-carbon energy technologies and other forms of climate mitigation tend to involve disempowerment and environmental injustices of various kinds. This paper argues that such tendencies are inherent in the social rationale of technological systems promoted by the logic of the world market. The production and operation of technological artifacts are imbued with economic rationality and must not be conceptualised as distinct from the organisation of society. This is illustrated by the energy transition that occurred during the Industrial Revolution, in which the underlying incentives of ecologically unequal exchange and environmental load displacements were transmuted into seemingly neutral concerns of economic rationality and technological progress. The distributive dimensions of markets and technologies become apparent as we now aspire to abandon the fossil energy regime, revealing how our concepts of ‘energy’ and ‘technology’ may obscure global processes of appropriation of human labour time and natural space. Such processes are as insidiously inscribed in low-carbon energy technologies as in the fossil-fueled technologies that they are intended to replace. To identify such pervasive injustices as inherent in technologies rather than contextual contingencies requires an acknowledgement of the social essence of technical artifacts. This in turn requires a deep transdisciplinarity that links physics, industrial ecology, the philosophy of technology, social theory, world trade, and the history of ideas. Current efforts to transcend the distinction between the social and the material pervasively fail to integrate social theory and physical resource theory. Rather than investigate the social and ecological repercussions of technological systems, the focus of energy justice research should be to discover the tacit, distributive functions that are inscribed in the technologies to begin with.
  •  
20.
  • Aaheim, Asbjørn, et al. (author)
  • Requirements to metrics of greenhouse gas emissions, given a cap on temperature
  • 2017
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 131, s. 460-467
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • The literature on metrics to measure contributions to climate change from emissions of different greenhouse gases divides into studies that highlight physical aspects and studies that show the importance of economic factors. This paper distinguishes the physical aspects and implications of economic factors by asking what is demanded from physically based metrics if used for a specific policy objective. We study the aim of maximizing the welfare of emissions generated by consumption when there is a limit to the increase in global mean temperature. In that case, metrics ought to change over time, with increasing weight on short-living gases before the temperature limit is met. Metrics for short-living gases increase also with increasing uncertainty. Adjustments to new information spur higher metrics for short-living gases if it reduces the expected allowable emissions before the target is met, and lower metrics in the opposite case. Under a binding target, metrics refer to the instantaneous impact on radiative forcing multiplied by the lifetime of the respective gases, and adjusted by the attitude to risk.
  •  
21.
  • Agneman, Gustav, et al. (author)
  • On the nexus between material and ideological determinants of climate policy support
  • 2024
  • In: ECOLOGICAL ECONOMICS. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 219
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This study explores how rising economic costs of climate mitigation policies differentially shape climate policy support among the political left and right. To this end, we randomly manipulate how much consumption costs increase as a result of four different climate mitigation policies and study how different cost scenarios influence policy support among a sample of 1,597 Swedish adults. We find that more costly climate policies induce greater climate policy polarization, since right -leaning participants display both lower baseline and more cost -sensitive climate policy support. In addition, we investigate how policy costs affect participants' concerns about the climatic consequences of consumption. While inconclusive, the results indicate that rightleaning participants, in some instances, display less concern about the climatic consequences of consumption when policy costs rise. This pattern can be understood through the lens of motivated disbelief, which holds that people adjust their beliefs in order to support their preferred actions. The present study provides novel insights as to how and when material conditions influence climate policy preferences.
  •  
22.
  • Ahlroth, Sofia, et al. (author)
  • Sustainable energy prices and growth : Comparing macroeconomic and backcasting scenarios
  • 2007
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 63:4, s. 722-731
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • How do results from the sustainability research world of backcasting relate to the macroeconomic scenarios used for policy evaluation and planning? The answer is that they don't, mostly - they come from different scientific traditions and are not used in the same contexts. Yet they often deal with the same issues. We believe that much can be gained by bringing the two systems of thinking together. This paper is a first attempt to do so, by making qualitative comparisons between different scenarios and highlighting benefits and limitations to each of them. Why are the pictures we get of the energy future so different if we use a macroeconomic model from when using a backcasting approach based on sustainable energy use? It is evident that the methods for producing those two kinds of scenarios differ a lot, but the main reason behind the different results are found in the starting points rather than in the methods. Baseline assumptions are quite different, as well as the interpretations and importance attached to signals about the future. in this paper, it is discussed how those two types of scenarios differ and how they approach issues such as energy prices and growth. The discussion is based on a comparison between Swedish economic and sustainability scenarios. The economic scenarios aim at being forecasts of the future and are used as decision support for long-term policies. But are the assumptions in the economic scenarios reasonable? The sustainability scenarios are explicitly normative backcasting scenarios. They do not take the issue of growth and consumption fully into account. Could they be developed in this respect? The comparison between the scenarios is also used to look closer at the issue of energy prices in a society with sustainable energy use. One of the questions raised is if a low energy society calls for high energy prices. Moreover, the effects of tradable permits versus energy taxes is analysed in the context of how energy use could be kept low in a growing economy.
  •  
23.
  • Albers, R. I., et al. (author)
  • A review of the spatial economics of non-timber forest product extraction: Implications for policy
  • 2013
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009. ; 92, s. 87-95
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Patterns of forest cover and forest degradation determine the size and types of ecosystem services forests provide. Particularly in low-income countries, nontimber forest product (NTFP) extraction by rural people, which provides important resources and income to the rural poor, contributes to the level and pattern of forest degradation. Although recent policy, particularly in Africa, emphasizes forest degradation, relatively little research describes the spatial aspects of NTFP collection that lead to spatial degradation patterns. This paper reviews both the spatial empirical work on NTFP extraction and related forest degradation patterns, and spatial models of behavior of rural people who extract NTFPs from forest. Despite the impact of rural people's behavior on resulting quantities and patterns of forest resources, spatial-temporal models/patterns rarely inform park siting and sizing decisions, econometric assessments of park effectiveness, development projects to support conservation, or REDD protocols. Using the literature review as a lens, we discuss the models' implications for these policies with particular emphasis on effective conservation spending and leakage.
  •  
24.
  • Alfredsson, Eva, et al. (author)
  • Real capital investments and sustainability : - The case of Sweden
  • 2019
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 161, s. 216-224
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Real capital investments are important for a transition to a more sustainable economy and for the continuous process of creative destruction and economic development. At the same time investments have negative environmental effects. In this paper we analyze to what extent the current investments in real capital (i.e.,buildings, machinery and infrastructures) in Sweden are sustainable in regard of the most important resources used in investments and in terms of CO2 emissions. This is evaluated based on Sweden's share of a sustainable use of these resources and our share of the remaining carbon budget for achieving the Paris agreement. In the analysis we have used best publicly available data and methods to indicatively establish sustainable levels of resource use and emissions. We find that 1 million invested SEK (US$ 110,000) generate 15–75 tonnes of CO2 emissions and use 80–260 MWh of energy, and on average 4.8 tonnes of iron, 0.2 tonnes of aluminum, 260 tonnes of gravel and sand and 6 tonnes of timber. Our analysis shows that within 50 years current investment would use up Sweden's CO2 budget available for achieving the Paris agreement, leaving no room for emissions from consumption. The use of timber, gravel and sand is above Sweden's share of a global yearly sustainable production. The current use of iron and aluminum can be maintained for 20–50 years, but approaches the sustainability criteria with a 200 year perspective.
  •  
25.
  • Alpizar, Francisco, 1974, et al. (author)
  • Reputation and household recycling practices: Field experiments in Costa Rica
  • 2015
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009. ; 120, s. 366-375
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Pro-environmental behavior is the willingness to cooperate and contribute to environmental public goods. A good understanding of why individuals undertake pro-environmental actions is important in order to construct policies that are aligned with preferences and actual behavioral patterns, such as concern for social esteem and reputation. In this paper, we present the results of a framed field experiment that explores reputation formation as a driver in support of household recycling practices. We use a "shame" and a "pride" treatment to test which is more effective, if at all, in increasing recycling effort. We find that reputational concerns indeed play a role in shaping individual pro-environmental behavior. Surprisingly, subjects cooperate more if the situation is framed as avoiding shame (bad reputation) rather than as acquiring pride and gratitude (good reputation). The actual experiment is based on a real recycling program, with participants who are heads of urban households in Costa Rica. (C) 2015 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
  •  
26.
  •  
27.
  • Andersson, Anna, et al. (author)
  • The effect of eco-certification on demand: The case of MSC-certified Norway lobster
  • 2023
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 204
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • We investigate if Marine Stewardship Council (MSC) certified Norway lobster fishing vessels in Sweden got higher prices and sold larger quantities after certification was introduced in 2015. Using detailed daily panel data and exploiting the fact that the same fishing water contains both certified and non-certified vessels, we use a difference-in-difference model for analysing demand effects of MSC-certification. We find a price premium the first months after the launch of the certification scheme for the initial adopters. However, this price premium dissipates over time and is mainly found for trawler vessels. For trawlers, we also find a negative effect on sold quantities the first months after certification but a positive effect a few years after certification. Creelers, on the other hand, got a positive effect on quantities sold both immediately after certification and after a few years. No general effect of MSC certification is found on neither prices nor quantities when the entire period January 2012 – January 2018 is investigated.
  •  
28.
  • Andersson, David, 1979, et al. (author)
  • Greenhouse gas emissions and subjective well-being: An analysis of Swedish households
  • 2014
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009. ; 102, s. 75-82
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • In the contemporary discussion on society's transformation towards long-termclimate targets, it is often implicitly assumed that behavioral changes, unlike technological changes, would lead to reductions in human wellbeing.However, this assumption has been questioned by researchers, who instead argue that people may live better lives by consuming less and reduce their environmental impact in the process. In this study we explore the relationship between greenhouse gas emissions and subjective well-being, using a sample of 1000 Swedish respondents.Our results show that there is no strong link between an individual's emissions and subjectivewellbeing. We also analyze the relationship between specific emission-intensive activities and subjective well-being and find thatnone of the activities examined correlates with subjective well-being. Finally, we explore a hypothesis put forward in the literature, suggesting that a poor work-life balance, long commuting distances, and materialistic values may decrease individuals' subjective well-being and increase greenhouse gas emissions. Our results indicate that materialistic values do correlate with lower levels of well-being and to some extent also with highergreenhouse gas emissions.
  •  
29.
  • Andersson, Fredrik N G (author)
  • Economic inequality and the ecological footprint: Time-varying estimates for four developed economies, 1962–2021
  • 2024
  • In: Ecological Economics. - 0921-8009. ; 220
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This paper explores the link between income, and wealth inequality and the ecological footprint in France, Netherlands, United States, and United Kingdom from 1962 to 2021. Based on theoretical considerations, we allow the relationship to vary over time. Our analysis provides some support for income inequality influencing ecological footprints, specifically through carbon emissions. Yet, we do not observe a significant effect on non‑carbon footprints. Notably, the link between income inequality and carbon emissions shifted from negative in the 1960s to positive from the late 1980s onwards. Over all our findings imply that economic inequality's impact on the environment is likely limited and context dependent.
  •  
30.
  • Andersson, Fredrik N G (author)
  • Income inequality and carbon emissions in the United States 1929–2019
  • 2023
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009. ; 204:A
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This paper studies the relationship between income inequality and carbon emissions in the United States between 1929 and 2019. We contribute to the literature by studying if and how the relationship has varied over time. To this end we estimate a band spectrum regression model and a smooth-varying coefficients model. Our results show that higher inequality was associated with lower emissions during the early part of the sample and higher emissions towards the end of the sample.
  •  
31.
  •  
32.
  • Angelstam, Per (author)
  • Choice experiment assessment of public preferences for forest structural attributes
  • 2015
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 119, s. 8-23
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Combining the approach used in landscape research with non-market valuation techniques, the aim of this study is to document human habitat selection for recreational purposes in a gradient of forest naturalness. The results indicate that respondents prefer older stands with vertical layering, irregularly spaced trees and a greater number of tree species. Our study thus indicates that forests that are managed (or left unmanaged) for biodiversity purposes are also likely to be attractive to humans. To conclude, while greater management intensity was associated with higher disutility regardless of the model employed, we do not perceive a risk of conflict between forest management designed to protect biodiversity and management targeting recreational value. Consequently, there is a need for spatially differentiated forest management that discriminates among different functions. The state ownership of all larger Polish forest massifs makes this zoning approach feasible. (C) 2015 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
  •  
33.
  • Arora Jonsson, Seema (author)
  • Does resilience have a culture? Ecocultures and the politics of knowledge production
  • 2016
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 121, s. 98-107
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Culture, that for long had been a neglected concept in resilience thinking, has gained prominence in recent times, especially in the notion of ecocultures/ecocultural resilience to be achieved through transdisciplinary projects. In this paper, I conceptualize the relation of science with society and culture that resilience scholars propose as part of a larger agenda of the integration of science with different knowledge and epistemologies. In order to understand how resilience thinking relates to culture, I investigate the culture of resilience itself. Using the lens of cultural and science studies, I go back to the history and context of resilience and transdisciplinarity, examine some of the central tools and concepts in resilience thinking and its entanglements in the politics of the past and present. In light of the discussion, I argue that we need to 'situate' rather than 'integrate' our knowledge production. This entails not only recognizing our own culture but also being open to different ways of knowing and to be able to transgress resilience. Moving away from integration and embracing ambivalence and humility can open up to experimental practices and trading places' in order to engage with nature and others justly. (C) 2015 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
  •  
34.
  • Ayres, Robert U., 1932, et al. (author)
  • A theory of economic growth with material/energy resources and dematerialization: Interaction of three growth mechanisms
  • 2005
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009. ; 55:1, s. 96-118
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • The nature of energy and material resources in a non-optimizing growth theory framework is clarified. This involves two modifications of the conventional theory. Firstly, multiple feedback mechanisms or "growth engines" are identified, such that the impact of the cost of production through demand on growth is accounted for. Secondly, a production function distinguishes between resource use, technical efficiency, and value creation. The resulting model is analytically solved under the condition of a constant growth rate. Given model complexity, numerical experiments are performed as well, providing relevant insights to the academic and political debates on 'environmental Kuznets curves' and 'dematerialization.'
  •  
35.
  • Bagliani, Marco, et al. (author)
  • A consumption-based approach to environmental Kuznets curves using the ecological footprint indicator
  • 2008
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 65:3, s. 650-661
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Recent research suggests that consumption-based measures offer an insightful perspective on the debate on the relationship between economic growth and the environment. In this article we deepen the consumption-based line of inquiry by investigating the empirical evidence in support of the environmental Kuznets hypothesis using 2001 ecological footprint data for 141 countries. We perform Ordinary Least Squares and Weighted Least Squares analysis on linear, quadratic and cubic functions, in standard and logarithmic specifications, as candidate models to represent the relationship between per capita income and environmental pressure. We replicate the cross country analysis also by estimating the regression function directly, through a nonparametric regression. In our analyses, with and without weighing data by population, the results do not show evidence of de-linking. (C) 2008 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
  •  
36.
  • Bali Swain, Ranjula, et al. (author)
  • Regulation, governance and the role of the informal sector in influencing environmental quality?
  • 2020
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 173
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • We investigate the effect of the informal sector and a range of governance indicators on both global and local pollutants for a panel of 58 countries during 1996-2011. The analysis employs a fixed effects-instrumental variable generalized method of moments approach. We find that the size of the informal sector has a significant impact on environmental quality, which is conditional on the level of economic development. For developing countries, the informal sector has a significant positive impact on local pollutants, whereas for the developed countries the informal sector has a significantly negative effect on global pollutants. The findings also reveal that the impact of governance depends on the type of governance measure, the level of economic development and type of pollutant. Control of corruption emerges as the single most important factor especially in the non-OECD countries in improving environmental quality. We argue that the efficacy of an environmental policy for a country with a large informal sector will be low if the policy measures do not address governance, size of the informal sector and environmental policy targets.
  •  
37.
  • Barthel, Stephan, 1968-, et al. (author)
  • The potential of ‘Urban Green Commons’ in the resilience building of cities
  • 2013
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 86, s. 156-166
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • While cultural diversity is increasing in cities at a global level as a result of urbanization, biodiversity is decreasing with a subsequent loss of ecosystem services. It is clear that diversity plays a pivotal role in the resilience building of ecosystems; however, it is less clear what role cultural diversity plays in the resil- ience building of urban systems. In this paper we provide innovative insights on how common property sys- tems could contribute to urban resilience building. Through a review of recent findings on urban common property systems and the relevant literature, we deal with urban green commons (UGCs) and discuss their potential to manage cultural and biological diversity in cities. We describe three examples of UGCs, i.e. col- lectively managed parks, community gardens, and allotment areas, with a focus on their institutional characteristics, their role in promoting diverse learning streams, environmental stewardship, and social– ecological memory. We discuss how UGCs can facilitate cultural integration through civic participation in urban land-management, conditions for the emergence of UGCs, the importance of cognitive resilience building, and what role property-rights diversity plays in urban settings. We conclude by elucidating some key insights on how UGCs can promote urban resilience building.
  •  
38.
  • Barthel, Stephan, 1968-, et al. (author)
  • Urban gardens, agriculture, and water management : Sources of resilience forlong-term food security in cities
  • 2013
  • In: Ecological Economics. - Amsterdam : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 86, s. 224-234
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Food security has always been a key resilience facet for people living in cities. This paper discusses lessons for food security fromhistoric and prehistoric cities. The Chicago school of urban sociology established amodernist understanding of urbanism as an essentialist reality separate from its larger life-support system. However, different urban histories have given rise to a remarkable spatial diversity and temporal variation viewed at the global and long-term scales that are often overlooked in urban scholarship.Drawing on two case studies fromwidely different historical and cultural contexts – the Classic Maya civilization of the late first millennium AD and Byzantine Constantinople – this paper demonstrates urban farming as a pertinent feature of urban support systems over the long-term and global scales. We show how urban gardens, agriculture, and water management as well as the linked social–ecological memories of how to uphold such practices over time have contributed to long-term food security during eras of energy scarcity. We exemplify with the function of such local blue–green infrastructures during chocks to urban supply lines. We conclude that agricultural production is not “the antithesis of the city," but often an integrated urban activity that contribute to the resilience of cities.
  •  
39.
  • Barthtel, Stephan, 1968-, et al. (author)
  • Urban Gardens, Agricultures and Waters : Sources of Resilience for Long-Term Food Security in Cities
  • 2013
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 86, s. 224-234
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Food security has always been a key resilience facet for people living in cities. This paper discusses lessons for food security from historic and prehistoric cities. The Chicago school of urban sociology established a modernist understanding of urbanism as an essentialist reality separate from its larger life-support system. However, different urban histories have given rise to a remarkable spatial diversity and temporal variation viewed at the global and long-term scales that are often overlooked in urban scholarship. Drawing on two case studies from widely different historical and cultural contexts - the Classic Maya civilization of the late first millennium AD and Byzantine Constantinople - this paper demonstrates urban farming as a pertinent feature of urban support systems over the long-term and global scales. We show how urban gardens, agriculture, and water management as well as the linked social-ecological memories of how to uphold such practices over time have contributed to long-term food security during eras of energy scarcity. We exemplify with the function of such local blue-green infrastructures during chocks to urban supply lines. We conclude that agricultural production is not "the antithesis of the city," but often an integrated urban activity that contribute to the resilience of cities.
  •  
40.
  • Bengtsson, Jan, et al. (author)
  • Towards valuation of biodiversity in agricultural soils: A case for earthworms
  • 2019
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 159, s. 291-300
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Soil biodiversity is deteriorating in Europe due to an on-going intensification of agriculture, climate change and food production supporting measures of the European Common Agricultural Policy (CAP). Nevertheless, the CAP tries to take biodiversity into account via proposing a range of agri-environmental measures. These ES contribute to food security, climate change mitigation, water retention and plant biomass growth. Healthy soils also help to prevent erosion, desertification, and landslides and to stabilise crop yields. The provision of ES by soil biota is a result of their impact on soil processes in interaction with soil conditions as well as soil management practices of the farmers such as tillage or crop rotations. Some taxa amongst soil biota play key roles in regulating soil processes. With respect to biocontrol of soil-borne pests, the earthworm species Lumbricus terrestris is known to play an important role in suppressing toxigenic plant pathogens, such as Fusarium culmorum and its mycotoxin deoxynivalenol (DON). We highlight the importance of earthworms for pest control to conceptualise and show how farmers' management practices influence soil ecosystem services and outline how this can be examined in a socio-ecological context by providing a concrete example of an economical evaluation of ES provided by earthworms.
  •  
41.
  • Bergek, Anna, 1973-, et al. (author)
  • The impact of environmental policy instruments on innovation : A review of energy and automotive industry studies
  • 2014
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 106, s. 112-123
  • Research review (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Various types of policy instruments have been implemented to reduce local and global emissions, but the impact on innovation of different instruments has received less attention. This paper reviews empirical studies of the innovation impact of four main types of policy instruments in two high-emitting sectors. The conclusions are threefold. (1) Policy plays a key role for the development and diffusion of environmental innovation in the studied sectors. (2) Different types of instruments promote different types of innovations: general economic instruments has primarily encouraged incremental innovation, general regulatory instruments has enforced improvements based on modular innovation, and technology-specific instruments appears to have been needed to support the development and deployment of radically new technologies. (3) All types of policy instruments face challenges in design and implementation: understanding the selection impact of the chosen instruments, implementing increasing stringency levels, committing to an appropriate scale, and safeguarding policy stability.
  •  
42.
  • Berglund, Christer (author)
  • The assessment of households' recycling costs : the role of personal motives
  • 2006
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 56:4, s. 560-569
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This paper analyzes households' perceptions of recycling activities in a municipality in northern Sweden, Piteå. The purpose of the paper is to analyze whether moral motives matter for the assessment of households' waste sorting costs. Data were gathered using a mail-out survey to 850 randomly chosen individuals in the municipality of Piteå, Sweden. We employ an economic model of moral motivation and econometric techniques. The main result that follows from the analysis is that the results support the notion that moral motives significantly lower the costs associated with household recycling efforts.
  •  
43.
  • Bergquist, Ann-Kristin, et al. (author)
  • Command-and-control revisited : environmental compliance and technological change in Swedish industry 1970-1990
  • 2013
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 85, s. 6-19
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This paper addresses the issue of environmental policy instrument choice for achieving deep emission reductions in the industrial sector. Specifically, it provides: (a) a theoretical and empirical review of the conditions under which performance standards can provide efficient incentives for deep emission reductions and technology adoption; and (b) an analysis of the design and the outcomes of the standards-based regulation of industrial pollutants in Sweden during the period 1970–1990. Our empirical findings suggest that the Swedish regulatory approach comprised many key elements of an efficient policy-induced transition towards radically lower emissions in the metal smelting and pulp and paper industries. The regulation relied solely on performance standards, thus granting flexibility to firms in terms of selecting the appropriate compliance measures. These standards were implemented in combination with extended compliance periods. R&D projects and the new knowledge that was advanced incrementally in interaction between the company, the environmental authorities and research institutions provided a direct catalyst to the regulatory process. In these ways the Swedish regulatory approach provided scope for creative solutions, environmental innovation, and permitted the affected companies to coordinate pollution abatement measures with productive investments.
  •  
44.
  • Biermann, Frank (author)
  • Planetary boundaries and earth system governance: Exploring the links
  • 2012
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009. ; 81, s. 4-9
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This article discusses the concept of planetary boundaries that has been advanced by a group of leading experts around Johan Rockstrom. I place the concept of planetary boundaries in the larger framework of the emerging research paradigm of earth system governance, welcoming it as a crucial contribution that defines the overall goals of governance. Yet I also elaborate on the political conflicts that surround the identification of planetary boundaries, which are, in the end, a social construct. I then explore the policy and governance responses that may follow from the planetary boundary approach. In the conclusion, I point to several research challenges that flow from the current state of knowledge on planetary boundaries. (C) 2012 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
  •  
45.
  • Birkin, F., et al. (author)
  • The relevance of epistemic analysis to sustainability economics and the capability approach
  • 2013
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009. ; 89, s. 144-152
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This paper considers how epistemic analyses (Birkin and Polesie, 2011; Foucault, 1970, 1990a, 1990b) may assist with the development of sustainability economics (Bartelmus, 2010; Baumgartner and Quaas, 2010a, 2010b; and Soderbaum, 2011) and the capability approach (Ballet et al., 2011; Martins, 2011; Rauschmayer and Lessmann, 2011; Scerri, 2012). It was the French social theorist Michel Foucault (1926-1984) who coined the term "episteme" to refer to the "possibility of knowledge" that determines the development of thought and knowledge in a given period. For Foucault epistemes were the "buried" foundations of knowledge that his epistemic "archaeology" could unearth. In 2007, Foucault was identified as the most cited author of books in the humanities by Thomson Reuters' ISI Web of Science. This paper begins with a brief definition and description of epistemic analyses. A summary analysis of the Modern episteme and neoclassical economics is then provided and this is followed by outline evidence for the emerging episteme. Finally the opportunity is considered for the emerging episteme to reinforce and enhance sustainability economics and the capability approach. (C) 2013 Elsevier B.V. All rights reserved.
  •  
46.
  • Bonilla, Jorge, 1975, et al. (author)
  • Refunded Emission Payments and Diffusion of NOx Abatement Technologies in Sweden
  • 2015
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009. ; 116, s. 132-145
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This paper studies how different NOx abatement technologies have diffused under the Swedish system of refunded emission payments (REP) and analyzes the determinants of the time to adoption. The policy, under which the charge revenues are refunded back to the regulated firms in proportion to energy output, was explicitly designed to affect investment in NOx-reducing technologies. The main finding is that REP had a significant effect on the adoption of post-combustion technologies. Moreover, we also find some indications that the effects of REP have been enhanced by the existing system of individual emission standards. In particular, the effect of REP speeding up the pace of adoption of post-combustion technologies is considerably larger in those counties where stringent standards are in place.
  •  
47.
  • Boons, Frank, et al. (author)
  • Conceptualizing sustainable development and global supply chains
  • 2012
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009. ; 83, s. 134-143
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • This paper introduces a holistic approach to the study of sustainable development of global product chains. We first present a number of perspectives on this topic from disciplines such as economic geography, management science, sociology and environmental sciences. Each of these approaches brings in a specific focus: the consequences of geographical dispersion of economic activities, measurement of ecological and social impact, managing sustainability in supply chains, and power asymmetry among economic actors. Until now, these disciplinary research lines have remained unconnected. We argue that ecological economics provides a promising background for a more holistic conceptualization. To this end, we formulate five basic questions that serve to advance the study of sustainability throughout the product chain by connecting the foci of the identified scientific disciplines. The aim of advancing a holistic perspective has guided the selection of papers for this special subsection, which are introduced throughout the text.
  •  
48.
  • Bostedt, Göran, 1966-, et al. (author)
  • Accounting for cultural heritage : A theoretical and empirical exploration with focus on Swedish reindeer husbandry
  • 2010
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 69:3, s. 651-657
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • The aim of this paper is to explore some of the theoretical and empirical aspects of an economy which includes cultural capital. We use a simple dynamic growth model and the concept of a social accounting matrix (SAM) to illustrate how the addition of income flows and net changes of various natural and cultural resources can be incorporated into a broader measure of welfare. The Swedish reindeer industry, managed by the indigenous Sami people, is used as an example since it is generally regarded to have significant cultural heritage value, beyond its contribution to conventional national accounts. We discuss a theoretically correct compensation to a cultural sector for preserving and maintaining a cultural heritage. Furthermore, we attempt to estimate the cultural value of the Sámi Reindeer sector in Sweden using a CVM survey. The results suggest that the willingness to pay (per year) to maintain cultural heritage at least at the current level may be quite substantive, estimates showing it can be several times the industry's turnover per year.
  •  
49.
  • Bostedt, Göran, 1966-, et al. (author)
  • Estimating cost functions for the four large carnivores in Sweden
  • 2008
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier. - 0921-8009 .- 1873-6106. ; 68:1-2, s. 517-524
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • The Swedish carnivore policy goal for the four large carnivores – wolverine (Gulo gulo), wolf (Canis lupus), brown bear (Ursus arctos) and lynx (Lynx lynx) – is to ensure a minimum viable population on a long-term basis. To reach this goal the policy restricts population regulation activities, like hunting (prohibited for wolverine and wolf and restricted for brown bear and lynx) in Sweden. For owners of semi-domesticated (i.e. reindeer), and domesticated (livestock) animals this policy and the existence of individuals of these four species results in externalities associated with predation.This paper presents econometric estimates of the predation and the social costs for these four species, based on ecological models of functional response. The data on costs is based on compensation provided to livestock owners by the Swedish government. The paper also applies these econometric estimates to predict the social cost per species when the population goals of the Swedish carnivore policy are reached. Based on out our model the wolverine and the lynx will impose the highest marginal, as well as total costs on society, given the current policy goals. The wolf is an efficient predator, but due to its geographical distribution in Sweden, its social costs are less than anticipated. The brown bear is largely omnivorous, thus resulting in relatively low social costs.
  •  
50.
  • Brunner, Florentine, 1991, et al. (author)
  • Carbon Label at a University Restaurant – Label Implementation and Evaluation
  • 2018
  • In: Ecological Economics. - : Elsevier BV. - 0921-8009. ; 146, s. 658-667
  • Journal article (peer-reviewed)abstract
    • Changes in human diets hold significant greenhouse gas emissions mitigation potential. In this paper, we use a field experiment to analyze the effects of implementing a label with greenhouse gas emission information for each dish at a restaurant. The traffic-light colored label was implemented in a student catering facility with 300–600 servings every day, and covered all seven dishes on offer. Individual level sales data including an anonymous identification number, gender, and age was collected both during the label phase and during a five-week control phase prior to the introduction of the label. We found that sales of green labeled (low emission) meat dishes increased by 11.5% compared to the control phase, whereas sales of red labeled meat dishes were reduced by 4.8%. Although the label had an effect on consumer behavior, emissions decreased modestly by 3.6%. We did not find evidence for different reactions to the label based on gender or age. © 2017 Elsevier B.V.
  •  
Skapa referenser, mejla, bekava och länka
  • Result 1-50 of 245
Type of publication
journal article (232)
review (8)
research review (5)
Type of content
peer-reviewed (232)
other academic/artistic (13)
Author/Editor
Gössling, Stefan (12)
Hornborg, Alf (8)
Schlüter, Maja (6)
Mauerhofer, Volker (5)
Söderholm, Patrik (4)
Folke, Carl (4)
show more...
Bostedt, Göran, 1966 ... (4)
Koch, Max (4)
Lindmark, Magnus, 19 ... (3)
Bodin, Örjan (3)
Hansson, Helena (3)
Söderqvist, Tore (3)
Gren, Ing-Marie (3)
Muchapondwa, Edwin (3)
Stage, Jesper (3)
Robinson, Elizabeth (3)
Alfredsson, Eva (3)
Malmaeus, Mikael (3)
Alpizar, Francisco, ... (3)
Elofsson, Katarina (3)
Ek, Kristina (3)
Persson, Martin, 197 ... (3)
Hahn, Tobias (3)
Carlsson, Fredrik, 1 ... (2)
Mont, Oksana (2)
Daw, Tim M. (2)
Lindmark, Magnus (2)
Roos, Andreas (2)
Köhlin, Gunnar, 1963 (2)
Höjer, Mattias (2)
Nilsson, Måns (2)
Martinsson, Peter, 1 ... (2)
Bravo, Giangiacomo (2)
Coria, Jessica, 1979 (2)
Heitzig, Jobst (2)
Hammarlund, Cecilia (2)
Hedenus, Fredrik, 19 ... (2)
Barthel, Stephan, 19 ... (2)
Colding, Johan (2)
Gomez-Baggethun, Eri ... (2)
Andersson, Fredrik N ... (2)
Lindahl, Therese (2)
Kuchler, Magdalena, ... (2)
Ayres, Robert U., 19 ... (2)
Bagliani, Marco (2)
Norberg, Jon (2)
Donges, Jonathan F. (2)
Hammer, Monica (2)
Bali Swain, Ranjula (2)
Wiedermann, Marc (2)
show less...
University
Lund University (58)
Stockholm University (40)
University of Gothenburg (29)
Swedish University of Agricultural Sciences (27)
Umeå University (24)
Royal Institute of Technology (22)
show more...
Uppsala University (19)
Luleå University of Technology (14)
Mälardalen University (11)
Chalmers University of Technology (10)
Linnaeus University (8)
Linköping University (7)
Södertörn University (7)
Mid Sweden University (5)
University of Gävle (4)
Stockholm School of Economics (3)
Jönköping University (2)
Högskolan Dalarna (2)
IVL Swedish Environmental Research Institute (2)
Kristianstad University College (1)
The Nordic Africa Institute (1)
RISE (1)
show less...
Language
English (244)
Swedish (1)
Research subject (UKÄ/SCB)
Social Sciences (180)
Natural sciences (80)
Engineering and Technology (20)
Agricultural Sciences (20)
Humanities (7)

Year

Kungliga biblioteket hanterar dina personuppgifter i enlighet med EU:s dataskyddsförordning (2018), GDPR. Läs mer om hur det funkar här.
Så här hanterar KB dina uppgifter vid användning av denna tjänst.

 
pil uppåt Close

Copy and save the link in order to return to this view